Fęrsluflokkur: Evrópumįl

Stöšvum strax ašlögun aš ESB - undirskriftasöfnun

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

         

Stöšvum strax ašlögun aš ESB.

 Skjaldarmerki Ķslands

Undirskriftalistinn

 

Žann 16. jślķ 2009, samžykkti Alžingi įlyktun um »aš leggja inn umsókn um ašild Ķslands aš ESB«. Įlyktunin hlaut samžykki Alžingis meš ašeins 33 atkvęšum af 63. Tillögu, um aš leita įlits žjóšarinnar į žessu afdrifarķka feilspori, var hafnaš meš 32 atkvęšum.

Umsóknin um ašild aš Evrópusambandinu var žannig alfariš į įbyrgš žess meirihluta į Alžingi sem studdi rķkisstjórn Jóhönnu Siguršardóttur. Umsóknin var hvorki į įbyrgš stjórnarandstöšnnar į Alžingi né žjóšarinnar.

Allt frį september 2009, hafa veriš geršar kannanir um afstöšu landsmanna til inngöngu landsins ķ ESB, af Capacent-Gallup. Nišurstöšur žessara kannana hafa įvallt veriš į einn veg, 60% - 70% žjóšarinnar hefur veriš andvķgt ašild.

Viš blasir, aš nśverandi meirihluti į Alžingi mun gjalda mikiš afhroš ķ kosningunum 27. aprķl 2013. Aš stórum hluta er žaš vegna žess aš žjóšin hafnar óskum rķkisstjórnarinnar um inngöngu landsins ķ ESB. Žjóšin hafnar žeim ólżšręšislegu vinnubrögšum sem rķkisstjórn Jóhönnu Siguršardóttur hefur višhaft ķ ESB mįlinu.

Viš undirrituš skorum į Alžingi aš stöšva strax višręšur Ķslands viš Evrópusambandiš um ašild Ķslands aš ESB, meš formlegri įlyktun. Alžingi hóf višręšur um ašild įn samžykkis žjóšarinnar og Alžingi ber skylda til aš ljśka žeim strax, įn kostnašarsamrar žjóšarkönnunar.



Sjįlfstęšisflokkur lofar landsmönnum vandfundnum gjöfum

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

Sjįlfstęšisflokkur lofar landsmönnum vandfundnum gjöfum.

Fyrst birt 22. aprķl 2013.

 

     

  

Loftur Altice Žorsteinsson.

Į kosningavef Sjįlfstęšisflokks er gerš grein fyrir loforšum flokksins um skatta-afslįtt til aš męta erfišri stöšu skuldugra heimila og til žeirra sem eru aš safna fyrir hśsnęši. Žessar hugmyndir eru svo ótrślegar aš nįlgast vitfirringu, ef sannar eru. Į vefsķšunni segir um skatta-afslįtt til aš lękka skuldir sem eru fyrir hendi:

»Lękkašu höfušstólinn meš skattaafslętti.

Žś fęrš allt aš 40.000 krónur į mįnuši ķ sérstakan skattaafslįtt vegna afborgana af ķbśšalįni. Skattaafslįtturinn fer beint inn į höfušstól lįnsins til lękkunar. Öllum stendur žessi leiš til boša.«

Ennfremur er lofaš skatta-afslętti til fjįrfestinga ķ hśsnęši ķ framtķšinni:

»Aušveldari leiš inn į fasteigna­markašinn.

Sjįlfstęšisflokkurinn vill veita žeim sem eru aš spara fyrir ķbśš allt aš 40 žśsund kr. skattaafslįtt į mįnuši af žeim tekjum sem er safnaš til ķbśšakaupa. Žannig geta sem flestar fjölskyldur fengiš tękifęri til aš eignast eigiš hśsnęši.

Dęmi: Sį sem leggur fyrir 100.000 krónur į mįnuši į sérstakan hśsnęšis­sparnašar­reikning fęr 40.000 króna skattaafslįtt į móti svo rįšstöfunartekjur minnka ašeins um 60.000. Žannig fęr fólk raunverulegan hvata til aš spara fyrir hśsnęšiskaupum.«

Svona örlęti hefur ekki sést ķ kosningabarįttu, allt frį landnįmi. Hlaupum samt ekki um ķ stjórnlausri gleši, heldur athugum hvaš žessi kosningaloforš merkja fyrir rķkissjóš.

Fyrir žaš fyrsta, žį er žarna talaš um aš einstaklingar fįi žennan rausnarlega skatta-afslįtt, en ekki til dęmis heimili eša bara skuldsettir einstaklingar. Žarna segir aš »Öllum stendur žessi leiš til boša

Ķ öšru lagi er skatta-afslįttinn hęgt aš fį vegna fyrirhugašra ķbśšarkaupa og einnig vegna afborgana af lįnum meš veši ķ hśsnęši. Hvaš ętli žessar fyrirhugušu gjafir leiši til mikilla śtgjalda fyrir rķkissjóš?

Einstaklingar ķ landinu voru 321.857 01. janśar 2013. Žar sem lofaš er afslętti upp į 480.000 kr/įri (40.000 x 12 mįnušir) veršur įrlegur skattaafslįttur vegna žessara loforša um 154 milljaršar (321.857 x 480.000). Vegna mannfjölgunar į nęrstu įrum mį örugglega hękka žessa tölu ķ 160 milljarša, hiš minnsta. Į žeim 5 įrum sem afslęttinum er lofaš, veršur afslįtturinn 800 milljaršar! Hefur rķkissjóšur efni į žessum gjöfum, eša er ętlunin aš bręša Snjóhengjuna og drekkja Hręgömmunum?

Frambjóšendur Flokksins hafa fjallaš opinberlega um framangreindar hugmyndir, en ķ staš kostnašar rķkissins upp į160 milljarša Króna, hafa žeir talaš um 16 milljarša. Žetta hlżtur aš vera kommu-skekkja, sem veršur snarlega leišrétt. Eftir stendur aš śtskżra hverju Flokkurinn er raunverulega aš lofa.

    


Fjölmenn samfylking Icesave-vina ętlar aš sitja įfram į Alžingi

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

Fjölmenn samfylking Icesave-vina ętlar aš sitja įfram į Alžingi.

Fyrst birt 22. aprķl 2013.

 

   

Loftur Altice Žorsteinsson.

Śrskuršur EFTA-dómstólsins frį 28. janśar 2013 stašfesti aš »Samstaša žjóšar gegn Icesave« og ašrir andstęšingar Icesave-kśgunarinnar höfšu fullkomlega rétt fyrir sér. Į sömu stundu og śrskuršurinn var geršur kunnur, hefšu allir žeir Alžingismenn sem greiddu Icesave-III-samningunum atkvęši įtt aš tilkynna afsögn sķna.

Enginn žessara žingmanna lét svo lķtiš, aš bišjast afsökunar į heimsku sinni og hugleysi frammi fyrir kröfugerš nżlenduvelda Evrópu. Žaš er jafnvel verra, aš stór hluti žessa óžjóšholla lišs bżšur sig fram til įframhaldandi setu į Alžingi. Samkvęmt skošanakönnunum, er lķklegt aš einhverjir žessara žjóšsvikara nįi kjöri. Lesendur eru hvattir til aš strika śt žetta fólk viš kosninguna, eftir žvķ sem fęri gefst.

 

 

 Žau sögšu Jį viš Icesave-III-lögunum, 16. febrśar 2011. 
  
  • Įrni Pįll Įrnason (S)
  • Įsta R. Jóhannesdóttir (S)
  • Björgvin G. Siguršsson (S)
  • Gušbjartur Hannesson (S)
  • Helgi Hjörvar (S)
  • Jóhanna Siguršardóttir (S)
  • Jónķna R. Gušmundsdóttir (S)
  • Katrķn Jślķusdóttir (S)
  • Kristjįn L. Möller (S)
  • Magnśs Orri Schram (S)
  • Möršur Įrnason (S)
  • Oddnż G. Haršardóttir (S)
  • Ólķna Žorvaršardóttir (S)
  • Róbert Marshall (S)
  • Sigmundur Ernir Rśnarsson (S)
  • Sigrķšur I. Ingadóttir (S)
  • Skśli Helgason (S)
  • Valgeršur Bjarnadóttir (S)
  • Žórunn Sveinbjarnardóttir (S)
  • Össur Skarphéšinsson (S)
 
 
  • Atli Gķslason (VG)
  • Įlfheišur Ingadóttir (VG)
  • Įrni Žór Siguršsson (VG)
  • Björn Valur Gķslason (VG)
  • Jón Bjarnason (VG)
  • Katrķn Jakobsdóttir (VG)
  • Lilja Rafney Magnśsdóttir (VG)
  • Ólafur Žór Gunnarsson (VG)
  • Steingrķmur J. Sigfśsson (VG)
  • Svandķs Svavarsdóttir (VG)
  • Žrįinn Bertelsson (VG)
  • Žurķšur Backman (VG)
  • Ögmundur Jónasson (VG)
  • Įrni Johnsen (D)
  • Įsbjörn Óttarsson (D)
  • Bjarni Benediktsson (D)
  • Einar K. Gušfinnsson (D)
  • Jón Gunnarsson (D)
  • Kristjįn Žór Jślķusson (D)
  • Ólöf Nordal (D)
  • Ragnheišur E. Įrnadóttir (D)
  • Ragnheišur Rķkharšsdóttir (D)
  • Tryggvi Žór Herbertsson (D)
  • Žorgeršur K. Gunnarsdóttir (D)
 


Žjóšnżting einkaskulda - almenningur blóšmjólkašur

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

Žjóšnżting einkaskulda - almenningur blóšmjólkašur.

Fyrst birt į vefsetri höfundar 23. marz 2012.

 

 

Lilja Mósesdóttir.

Kröfuhafar gömlu bankanna og śtrįsarvķkinganna leita enn leiša til aš koma kröfum sķnum yfir į skattgreišendur, ķ staš žess aš lįta gömlu bankana og śtrįsarvķkingana borga. Forusta stjórnarflokkanna hefur żtt undir žessa višleitni kröfuhafanna meš ķtrekušum naušsamningum um „Icesave skuldbindinguna“, andstöšu viš almennar skuldaleišréttingar sem hefšu rżrt eignir kröfuhafa og stušning viš gjaldeyrishöft sem koma ķ veg fyrir aš aflandskrónur og ašrar eignir kröfuhafa verši afskrifašar.

Į bak viš aflandskrónurnar og eignir kröfuhafa gömlu bankanna voru einkaskuldir fyrirtękja sem fóru ķ žrot. Žjóšarbśiš hefur žvķ ekki efni į aš greiša śt žessar aflandskrónur og eignir kröfuhafa. Rķkisstjórnin skilur ekki vandann og leyfir aflandskrónueigendum aš kaupa rķkisskuldabréf fyrir veršlitlar krónur eins og žęr hefšu fullt veršgildi. Žetta heitir aš žjóšnżta tapašar einkaskuldir. Skerša veršur lķfskjör almennings verulega ķ landinu ef žessum frošueignum veršur ekki žrżst śt śr hagkerfinu meš žvķ aš rżra virši žeirra meš hįum śtstreymisskatti, eša meš žvķ aš taka upp Nżkrónu (Rķkisdal) į mismunandi skiptigengi til aš rżra veršgildi žeirra.

Höft til verndar kröfuhöfum.

Sķfellt fleiri sérfręšingar taka nś undir tillögu mķna um skatt į śtstreymi fjįrmagns sem ég lagši m.a. til ķ grein ķ Fréttablašinu ķ lok október 2008. Tillögu minni var slįtraš af fólki sem veit ekkert um fjįrmįlakreppur og skilur ekki naušsyn žess aš skrifa nišur tapašar eignir sem notašar voru til aš fjįrmagna fjįrfestingar og neyslu fyrirtękja og einstaklinga sem nś eru gjaldžrota. Ķ staš t.d. 80% skatts į śtstreymi fjįrmagns voru innleidd gjaldeyrishöft sem vernda kröfuhafa gegn eignarżrnun og tryggja žeim hęstu įvöxtun sem völ er į ķ Evrópu. AGS rįšlagši stjórnvöldum aš styggja ekki eigendur žessara frošueigna. Aflandskrónueigendum var žvķ bošiš aš umbreyta frošueignum sķnum ķ rķkisskuldabréf įn afskrifta og meš hįrri įvöxtun. Įvöxtun sem sótt er ķ vasa skattgreišenda og skuldsettra heimila og fyrirtękja į Ķslandi. Eftir hrun hefur žjóšin ekki įtt gjaldeyri til aš kaupa krónueignir aflandskrónueigenda og kröfuhafa.

Śtflutningstekjurnar hafa fariš ķ aš greiša fyrir innflutning og vexti og afborganir af erlendum skuldum. Śtstreymi vaxtagreišslna af frošueignum sem eru į leiš śt śr hagkerfinu hefur veikt gengi krónunnar og gert endurfjįrmögnun erlendra lįna erfišari og dżrari en ella. Fljótlega žarf t.d. Nżi Landsbankinn aš endurfjįrmagna lįn aš upphęš um 320 milljarša. Naušsynlegt er aš fį nżtt erlent lįn til aš koma ķ veg fyrir aš žessi upphęš bętist ekki viš um 700 milljarša eignir aflandskrónueigenda og kröfuhafa gömlu bankanna sem sitja fastar į bak viš höftin og bķša žess aš fara śt. Śtstreymi sem setur mikinn žrżsting į krónuna til lękkunar. Höftin virka eins og vatnsaflsvirkjun sem lokar į śtstreymiš og į bak viš vegg virkjunarinnar safnast upp stöšugt hęrra stöšulón peninga. Stöšulón sem nśna er um 1.000 milljaršar en fer nišur ķ um 700 milljaršar um leiš og bśiš er aš tryggja endurfjįrmögnun Landsbankans.

Lķfskjörin ķ vasa kröfuhafa.

Sś leiš sem stjórnarflokkarnir hafa vališ til aš tryggja eignir aflandskrónueigenda og kröfuhafa er aš halda kaupmętti ķ landinu nišri og langt undir žvķ sem gerist hjį nįgrönnum okkar. Lķtill kaupmįttur almennings į Ķslandi dregur śr innflutningi vöru og žjónustu, žannig aš afgangur myndast į višskiptum viš śtlönd. Afgangurinn er notašur til aš fjįrmagna hęgfara śtstreymi frošueignanna. Miklar skuldir og vaxtagreišslur Ķslendska žjóšarbśsins gera žjóšinni sķfellt erfšara fyrir aš fjįrmagna hęgfara śtstreymi frošueigna og žvķ eru nś uppi raddir um aš veikja žurfi gengi krónunnar enn meira til aš fjįrmagna śtstreymiš. Enn į nż er m.ö.o. uppi krafa um aš styrkja skjaldborgina um fjįrmagnseigendur į kostnaš lķfskjaranna ķ landinu. Stjórnarflokkarnir viršast ekki sjį neina ašra leiš śt śr vandanum. Ef hin svokallaša norręna velferšarstjórn ętlar aš fara lķfskjaraskeršingarleišina, žį mun mikill fjöldi landsmanna sjį hag sżnum betur borgiš meš žvķ aš selja krónueigendum eignir sķnar į bóluverši og flytja žangaš žar sem lķfskjör eru višunandi.

Nżkróna (Rķkisdalur).

Skattlagningu į śtstreymi fjįrmagns hefur veriš hafnaš į žeirri forsendu aš skatturinn gangi į eignarrétt kröfuhafa og gegn įkvęši EES samningsins um frjįlst flęši fjįrmagns. Upptaka Nżkrónu (Rķkisdala) meš mismunandi skiptigengi er leiš framhjį žessum vandkvęšum. Launum fólks ķ landinu yrši breytt ķ Nżkrónu žannig aš upphęš žeirra yrši óbreytt. Frošueignir į leiš śt śr landi yrši hins vegar skipt yfir ķ Nżkrónu žannig aš 10 milljónir ķ gömlum krónum yršu t.d. 2 milljónir ķ Nżkrónum. Upptaka Nżkrónu myndi žannig laga ytra ójafnvęgi hagkerfsins sem birtist ķ žvķ aš žjóšin hefur ekki efni į aš kaupa krónueignir aflandskrónueigenda og kröfuhafa nema fella gengi krónunnar enn meira og skerša verulega lķfskjör almennings meš hęrra vöruverši og dżpkandi skuldakreppu heimilanna.

Jafnframt vęri naušsynlegt aš nota upptöku Nżkrónunnar til aš laga innra ójafnvęgi hagkerfisins sem felst ķ žvķ aš sumir eiga alltof miklar eignir (fjįrmagnseigendur og lķfeyrissjóšir) og ašrir eru of skuldsettir. Viš upptöku Nżkrónunnar žyrfti žvķ aš skrifa hśsnęšisskuldir žannig aš 10 milljón kr. lįn fęri yfir į 8 milljónum kr. og lękka eignir fjįrmagnseigenda til samręmis. Upptaka Nżkrónu (Rķkisdala) er ekki töfrabragš heldur naušsynleg varnarašgerš til aš koma ķ veg fyrir aukna fįtękt og stórfelldan landflótta į nęstu įrum.


Steve H. Hanke: The Dead Hand of Exchange Controls

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

Steve H. Hanke: The Dead Hand of Exchange Controls.

Fyrst birt ķ jślķ-hefti GlobeAsia 2010.

 

 

  

Steve H. Hanke.

The monetary bureaucrats in the United States, Europe and Japan have delivered ultra-low interest rates. When combined with the exchange-rate regimes in most Asian countries, these low interest rate policies have created a hot-money cocktail. In May, the United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific recommended the imposition of exchange controls to curb inflows of hot-money (styggur peningur) into the region. On June 13 and 16, South Korea and Indonesia, respectively, took the U.N. bait and introduced new exchange controls.

To understand the causes of hot-money flows, we must examine the basic types of exchange-rate regimes. Let’s take a look (see accompanying chart).

hanke-20080902-big

Free-Market Regimes.

Although floating and fixed rates appear dissimilar, they are members of the same free-market family. Both operate without exchange controls and are free-market mechanisms for balance-of-payments adjustments. With a floating rate, a central bank sets a monetary policy but has no exchange rate policy — the exchange rate is on autopilot. In consequence, the monetary base is determined domestically by a central bank. With a fixed rate there are two possibilities: either a currency board sets the exchange rate, but has no monetary policy — the money supply is on autopilot — or a country is “dollarized” and uses a foreign currency as its own.

Under a fixed-rate regime, a country’s monetary base is determined by the balance of payments, moving in a one-to-one correspondence with changes in its foreign reserves. With both of these free-market exchange rate mechanisms, there cannot be conflicts between monetary and exchange rate policies, and balance-of-payments crises (and hot-money flows) cannot rear their ugly heads. Floating- and fixed-rate regimes are inherently equilibrium systems in which market forces act to automatically rebalance financial flows and avert balance-of-payments crises and hot money flows.

Pegged Rates Invite Trouble.

Most economists use “fixed” and “pegged” as interchangeable or nearly interchangeable terms for exchange rates. While these two types are superficially similar, they are fundamentally very different types of exchange-rate arrangements. Pegged-rate systems are those where the monetary authority is aiming for more than one target at a time. Indeed, pegged rates require a central bank to manage both the exchange rate and monetary policy.

With a pegged rate, the monetary base contains both domestic and foreign components. Pegged systems — which include pegged, but adjustable rates, crawling pegs, and managed floating rates — go hand-in-glove with hot money flows. These systems often employ exchange controls and are not free-market mechanisms for international balance-of-payments adjustments. Pegged exchange rates (gengistylling) are inherently disequilibrium systems, lacking an automatic mechanism to produce balance-of-payments adjustments.

Unlike floating and fixed rates, pegged rates invariably result in conflicts between monetary and exchange rate policies. For example, when capital inflows become “excessive” under a pegged system, a central bank often attempts to sterilize the ensuing increase in the foreign component of the monetary base by selling bonds, reducing the domestic component of the base. And when outflows become “excessive,” a central bank attempts to offset the decrease in the foreign component of the base by buying bonds, increasing the domestic component of the monetary base.

Balance-of-payments crises erupt as a central bank begins to offset more and more of the reduction in the foreign component of the monetary base with domestically created base money. When this occurs, it is only a matter of time before currency speculators spot the contradictions between exchange rate and monetary policies (as they did in the Asian financial crisis of 1997—98) and force a devaluation, the imposition of exchange controls, or both.

Hot Money and Exchange Controls.

Hot money flows are principally associated with pegged exchange rates. Many analysts have misdiagnosed the so-called hot money problem because they have failed to appreciate this all-important linkage. In consequence, they have prescribed exchange controls as a cure-all to cool off the hot money. That prescription treats the symptoms. It fails to treat the disease: pegged exchange rates. Until pegged rates are abandoned, there will be volatile hot money flows and calls to cool the hot money with exchange controls.

Currency convertibility is a simple concept. It means residents and nonresidents are free to exchange domestic currency for foreign currency. However, there are many degrees of convertibility, with each denoting the extent to which governments impose controls on the exchange and use of currency.

The pedigree of exchange controls can be traced back to Plato, the father of statism (rķkisforsjį). Inspired by Lycurgus of Sparta, Plato embraced the idea of an inconvertible currency as a means to preserve the autonomy of the state from outside interference. It is no wonder that the leadership in Beijing finds the idea of an inconvertable yuan so attractive.

The temptation to turn to exchange controls in the face of disruptions caused by hot money flows is hardly new. Tsar Nicholas II first pioneered limitations on convertibility in modern times, ordering the State Bank of Russia to introduce, in 1905—06, a limited form of exchange control to discourage speculative purchases of foreign exchange. The bank did so by refusing to sell foreign exchange, except where it could be shown that it was required to buy imported goods. Otherwise, foreign exchange was limited to 50,000 German marks per person. The Tsar’s rationale for exchange controls was that of limiting hot money flows, so that foreign reserves and the exchange rate could be maintained. The more things change, the more they remain the same.

Before more politicians come under the spell of exchange controls, they should reflect on the following passage from Nobel laureate Friedrich Hayek’s 1944 classic, The Road to Serfdom:

The extent of the control over all life that economic control confers is nowhere better illustrated than in the field of foreign exchanges. Nothing would at first seem to affect private life less than a state control of the dealings in foreign exchange, and most people will regard its introduction with complete indifference. Yet the experience of most Continental countries has taught thoughtful people to regard this step as the decisive advance on the path to totalitarianism and the suppression of individual liberty. It is, in fact, the complete delivery of the individual to the tyranny of the state, the final suppression of all means of escape — not merely for the rich but for everybody.

Hayek’s message about convertibility has regrettably been overlooked by many contemporary economists. Exchange controls are nothing more than a ring fence within which governments can expropriate their subjects’ property. Open exchange and capital markets, in fact, protect the individual from exactions, because governments must reckon with the possibility of capital flight.

From this it follows that the imposition of exchange controls leads to an instantaneous reduction in the wealth of the country, because all assets decline in value. To see why, it is important to understand how assets are priced.

The value of any asset is the sum of the expected future installments of income it generates discounted to the present value. For example, the price of a stock represents the value to the investor now of his share of the company’s future cash flows, whether issued as dividends or reinvested. The present value of future income is calculated using an appropriate interest rate that is adjusted for the various risks that the income may not materialize.

When convertibility is restricted, risk increases, because property is held hostage and is subject to a potential ransom through expropriation. As a result, the risk-adjusted interest rate employed to value assets is higher than it would be with full convertibility. Investors are willing to pay less for each dollar of prospective income and the value of property is less than it would be with full convertibility.

This result, incidentally, is the case even when convertibility is allowed for profit remittances. With less than full convertibility, there is still a danger the government will confiscate property without compensation.

That explains why foreign investors are less willing to invest new money in a country with such controls, even with guarantees on profit remittances.

Investors become justifiably nervous when they expect that a government may impose exchange controls. Settled money becomes “hot” and capital flight occurs. Asset owners liquidate their property and get out while the getting is good. Contrary to popular wisdom, restrictions on convertibility do not retard capital flight, they promote it.

Full convertibility is the only guarantee that protects people’s right to what belongs to them. Even if governments are not compelled by arguments on the grounds of freedom, the prospect of seeing every asset in the country suddenly lose value as a result of exchange controls should give policymakers pause.

This brings us to China — a country with a plethora of exchange controls and an inconvertible currency. Beijing should adopt a fixed exchangerate regime. This would force Beijing to dump exchange controls and make the yuan fully convertible. Such a “Big Bang” would muzzle the China-bashers and put Beijing in the driver’s seat. After all, China would then have a stable, freemarket exchange-rate regime.

  

Anti-EU parties poised for victory in Iceland

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

Anti-EU parties poised for victory in Iceland.

Fyrst birt hjį EuropeanVoice.com 18. aprķl 2013.

 

 

  

 

Andrew Gardner.

 

Progressives could form single-party government.

The sole established pro-European Union party in Iceland, the governing Social Democrats (SDA), is set to be crushed in a highly volatile and potentially historic parliamentary election on 27 April.

 

The dominant question of a campaign in which the country's bid for EU membership has been largely marginalised, is now whether the centre-right Progressive Party can maintain the momentum that has taken it from 12.7% in the polls in December to 40.8% in early April. A small increase would enable it to form the first single-party government since Iceland gained full independence from Denmark in 1944.

 

An outright majority for the Progressives – or a coalition with the other right-wing party, the Independence Party – would result in a referendum on halting talks on EU membership immediately. Roughly two-thirds of Icelanders have consistently said they oppose joining the EU, but a thin majority want negotiations to be completed.

 

Observers attribute the revolution in the Progressive Party's fortunes to other parties' weaknesses, and to its determined opposition to a deal to compensate Dutch and British savers hit when the collapse of Landsbanki in 2008 resulted in losses for holders of its online Icesave account. In January, the court of the European Free-Trade Association ruled that Iceland did not have to reimburse depositors.

 

Loss of support.

The consistency of the Progressives' position has differentiated it from the performance of Bjarni Benediktsson, the leader of the Independence Party and for a long time the probable next premier. Before a 2011 referendum, Benediktsson had said voters should support a deal with London and The Hague as the best on offer. Sigmundur Gunnlaugsson, the Progressives' leader, has reinforced his advantage by maintaining discipline over a diverse party, in sharp contrast to the divisions within other parties.

 

The centre-left Social Democrats and the hard-left Left-Green Movement (LGM) joined forces to form a government in the wake of the 2008 economic crisis, which resulted in Iceland being put under an International Monetary Fund programme, now all but completed. However, the parties' differences over Europe – the LGM opposes accession – undermined the government. Four defections eventually reduced it to just 30 seats in the 63-seat Althingi.

 

Jóhanna Siguršardóttir, seen by many as a weak and ineffectual prime minister, has stepped down as party leader, as has the LGM's Steingrķmur Sigfśsson, but neither change has arrested the slide in support. In early April, the SDA had 9.7% and the LGM had 5.7%; in 2009, the SDA won 29.8% of the vote, and the LGM 21.7%.

 

The main beneficiary had long been expected to be the Independence Party, but a party conference in February contributed to its post-Icesave decline. A strongly anti-EU line emerged, including a resolution to close the EU's information office. That amplified doubts about the ability of Benediktsson, who became leader in 2009, to impose himself on a party that served in every government until 2009, and that led the country into the economic crisis.

 

While the Progressives have gained most from other parties' weaknesses, two new parties – Bright Future and the Pirate Party – should win enough votes to enter parliament.

 

The left-of-centre Bright Future looks likely to emerge in third place, making it the most powerful pro-EU party in parliament.

 

In coalition talks, the principal issue other than a referendum to end EU talks would be Iceland's policy on the determining EU-related issue for most Icelanders, management of fisheries. The one certainty is that a tough position will emerge.

 


Steve H. Hanke: Europe, A Troubled Region

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

Steve H. Hanke: Europe, A Troubled Region.

Fyrst birt ķ maķ-hefti GlobeAsia 2013.

 

 

Steve H. Hanke.

The most recent banking crisis in Europe erupted on the Island of Cyprus. Among other things, one result of the final EU-IMF bailout package was the imposition of capital controls, or restrictions on currency convertibility.

Currency convertibility is a simple concept. It means residents and nonresidents are free to exchange domestic currency for foreign currency. However, there are many degrees of convertibility, with each denoting the extent to which governments impose controls on the exchange and use of currency.

The pedigree of exchange controls can be traced back to Plato, the father of statism (rķkisforsjį). Inspired by Lycurgus of Sparta, Plato embraced the idea of an inconvertible currency as a means to preserve the autonomy of the state from outside interference.

The temptation to turn to exchange controls in the face of disruptions caused by hot money flows is hardly new. Tsar Nicholas II first pioneered limitations on convertibility in modern times, ordering the State Bank of Russia to introduce, in 1905–06, a limited form of exchange control to discourage speculative purchases of foreign exchange. The bank did so by refusing to sell foreign exchange, except where it could be shown that it was required to buy imported goods. Otherwise, foreign exchange was limited to 50,000 German marks per person. The Tsar’s rationale for exchange controls was that of limiting hot money flows, so that foreign reserves and the exchange rate could be maintained. The more things change, the more they remain the same.

Before more politicians come under the spell of exchange controls, they should reflect on the following passage from Nobel laureate Friedrich Hayek’s 1944 classic, The Road to Serfdom:

“The extent of the control over all life that economic control confers is nowhere better illustrated than in the field of foreign exchanges. Nothing would at first seem to affect private life less than a state control of the dealings in foreign exchange, and most people will regard its introduction with complete indifference. Yet the experience of most Continental countries has taught thoughtful people to regard this step as the decisive advance on the path to totalitarianism and the suppression of individual liberty. It is, in fact, the complete delivery of the individual to the tyranny of the state, the final suppression of all means of escape—not merely for the rich but for everybody.” 

Hayek’s message about convertibility has regrettably been overlooked by many contemporary economists. Exchange controls are nothing more than a ring fence within which governments can expropriate their subjects’ property. Open exchange and capital markets, in fact, protect the individual from exactions, because governments must reckon with the possibility of capital flight.

From this it follows that the imposition of exchange controls leads to an instantaneous reduction in the wealth of the country, because all assets decline in value. To see why, it is important to understand how assets are priced.

The value of any asset is the sum of the expected future installments of income it generates discounted to the present value. For example, the price of a stock represents the value to the investor now of his share of the company’s future cash flows, whether issued as dividends or reinvested. The present value of future income is calculated using an appropriate interest rate that is adjusted for the various risks that the income may not materialize.

When convertibility is restricted, risk increases, because property is held hostage and is subject to a potential ransom through expropriation. As a result, the risk-adjusted interest rate employed to value assets is higher than it would be with full convertibility. Investors are willing to pay less for each dollar of prospective income and the value of property is less than it would be with full convertibility.

This result, incidentally, is the case even when convertibility is allowed for profit remittances. With less than full convertibility, there is still a danger the government will confiscate property without compensation. That explains why foreign investors are less willing to invest new money in a country with such controls, even with guarantees on profit remittances.

Investors become justifiably nervous when they expect that a government may impose exchange controls. Settled money becomes ‘‘hot’’ and capital flight occurs. Asset owners liquidate their property and get out while the getting is good. Contrary to popular wisdom, restrictions on convertibility do not retard capital flight, they promote it.

That said, some proponents parade Malaysia’s 1998 experiment with capital controls as an example of the successful use of capital controls. This is simply nonsense. In 2006, Prof. Simon Johnson of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), et al. convincingly refuted claims of macroeconomic benefits resulting from Malaysia’s imposition of capital controls. In fact, he found that capital controls bred official corruption. As Prof. Andrei Shleifer of Harvard (2009) demonstrated, South Korea actually recovered “much faster” than Malaysia in the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis.

Full convertibility is the only guarantee that protects people’s right to what belongs to them. Even if governments are not compelled by arguments on the grounds of freedom, the prospect of seeing every asset in the country suddenly lose value as a result of exchange controls should give policymakers pause.

Unfortunately for Cyprus, capital controls are only the beginning of the bad news. European and Cypriot leaders have tried to assuage fears that the Cypriot economy will collapse by painting downplaying Cyprus’ impending GDP contraction. But, as a recently leaked report by the esteemed boutique investment bank Alvarez and Marsal confirms, this will not be the case. As the accompanying chart shows, Cyprus can expect to see a money supply deficiency of 13.54%.

In consequence, according to my estimate, Cyprus can expect GDP to contract by 12.2% in 2013. This will cause the so-called “good bank” – the Bank of Cyprus – which was set up as a part of the bail-in package, to probably go bust before long, wreaking even more havoc on the Cypriot financial sector, and the Cypriot economy.

The shockwaves, however, will be felt beyond the tiny island of Cyprus. Europe’s money supply is already reeling from the devastating credit crunch imposed via Basel III bank capital requirements, and a general loss of confidence in the aftermath of the European sovereign debt crisis (see the accompanying chart).

The latest crisis in Cyprus will only make things worse. As goes the money supply, so too goes the overall economy. Expect to see continued weak economic growth for the Eurozone going forward.

 


Aš bręša Snjóhengju og slökkva eignabruna er aušvelt meš fastgengi

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

Aš bręša Snóhengju og slökkva eignabruna er aušvelt meš fastgengi.

Fyrst birt ķ Morgunblašinu 17. aprķl 2013.

 

Loftur Altice Žorsteinsson.

Umręša um stęrstu vandamįl landsmanna einkennist af varšstöšu um sérhagsmuni. Hér er vķsaš til žeirra vandamįla sem stafa af Snjóhengju og vķsitölulįnum. Ķsland į ekki alvöru pening (gjaldeyri) til aš hleypa fram Snjóhengjunni. Žess ķ staš, veršur aš bręša hana og žaš višfangsefni er aušvelt, ef menn kunna til verka og vilja leysa vandann.

Eftir aš gengislįn voru dęmd ólögleg, liggur fyrir aš vķsitölulįn hljóta aš vera žaš einnig. Augljóst samband er į milli hękkana lįnavķsitölunnar og gengisbreytinga Krónunnar. Žetta samband er hęgt aš sanna stęršfręšilega og lįnavķsitalan er žvķ afleiša af flotgengi Krónunnar. Viš bankahruniš stökkbreyttist höfušstóll hśsnęšislįna og eignabruni fylgdi ķ kjölfariš.

Lįnavķsitölu hśsnęšislįna veršur žvķ aš fęra til baka, į sama hįtt og veriš er aš gera meš gengistryggšu lįnin. Hins vegar er ekki hęgt aš treysta į skilvirkni rķkiskerfisins og leišréttingar kunna aš taka langan tķma. Žaš leysingavatn sem losnar viš bręšslu Snjóhengjunnar er kęrkomiš tęki til aš stökkva eignabruna heimilanna.

Fastgengi aušveldar bręšslu Snjóhengjunnar.

Aš bręša Snjóhengjuna er aušveldast ķ skjóli fastgengis og upptaka fastgengis er einföld ašgerš. Fastgengi getur veriš af tveimur geršum, žaš er aš segja upptaka erlends gjaldmišils (Kanadadals), eša stofnun myntrįšs sem annast śtgįfu innlendrar myntar (Rķkisdals). Kostnašur viš stofnun myntrįšs veršur um 50 milljaršar Króna. Lagt er til, aš Sešlabankinn leggi til 45 milljarša ķ Kanadadölum til aš innleysa žęr Krónur sem hann er meš ķ umferš og aš rķkiš leggi til afganginn.

Til aš hraša upptöku fastgengis er einfaldast aš taka fyrst upp Kanadadal, sem hęgt er aš gera į einni viku. Aš 12 mįnušum lišnum hęfist sķšan starfsemi myntrįšs meš śtgįfu Rķkisdals. Bęši Rķkisdalur og Kanadadalur verša lögeyrir til frambśšar, en Krónan um takmarkašan tķma. Fastgengi meš fyrirkomlagi myntrįšs veršur aš festa ķ Stjórnarskrįna, til aš žaš hafi trśveršugleika. Žess vegna er hyggilegt aš ętla 12 mįnuši ķ undirbśning.

Vegna rangra upplżsinga, sem aš undanförnu hafa komiš fram, mį nefna aš einungis myntslįttur (sešlabankar eša myntrįš) gefa śt peninga.  Fjarstęša er aš halda fram, aš peningavelta višskiptabanka sé śtgįfa peninga. Engir peningar verša til viš aš ašilar skiptist į fjįrkröfum. Ef banna ętti bönkum aš endurlįna peninga sem žeir fį til varšveizlu, jafngilti žaš banni į starfsemi banka.

Sešlabanki og Samfylking standa vörš um sérhagsmuni.

Fram aš žessu hefur hugmyndum um fastgengi veriš vķsaš į bug, af Sešlabankanum og rķkisstjórn Jóhönnu Siguršardóttur. Hinum furšulegustu mótbįrum hefur veriš beitt, sem allar er aušvelt aš hrekja. Stašreyndin er sś aš žessir ašilar hafa veriš aš verja sérhagsmuni, sem eru ķ fullkominni andstöšu viš hagsmuni žjóšarinnar. Meš röngum fullyršingum um gjaldmišilsmįl eru Starfsmenn Sešlabankans aš vernda eigiš skinn. Allir vita, aš žegar tekiš veršur upp fastgengi og Sešlabankinn lagšur nišur mun fjölmennt starfsliš Sešlabankans verša aš leita sér annara starfa.

Samfylkingin er ofstękisfullur rétttrśar-söfnušur, sem notar žaš sem hendi er nęrst til aš réttlęta innlimum Ķslands ķ Evrópusambandiš. Žótt Evran verši ekki tekin upp įn ašildar aš ESB, talar Samfylking um fastgengi meš Evru, eins og ekki komi ašrir möguleikar til įlita. Gjarnan vķsa ESB-vinirnir til rangra fullyršinga Sešlabankans. Mįlflutningur žessara ašila er jafn innantómur og barįtta sömu ašila var ķ žįgu Icesave-kśgunar nżlenduveldanna.

Rķkisstjórn Jóhönnu Siguršardóttur skapaši Snjóhengjuna.

Neyšarlögin frį 06. október 2008 heimilušu rķkinu aš stofna og eiga nżgju bankana. Fyrirséš var aš bankarnir yršu gullnįma, vegna dulins eiginfjįr, sem stafaši af fyrirfram afskriftum og einokunar-ašstöšu į markašnum. Įn fyrirvara, afsalaši rķkisstjórnin bönkunum ķ hendur hręgamma og keypti sķšan einn žeirra aftur, meš 300 milljarša skuldabréfi ķ erlendum gjaldeyri. Žannig skapaši rķkisstjórnin Snjóhengjuna. Um sķšustu įramót var eiginfé bankanna žriggja yfir 500 milljaršar Króna.

Hręgammarnir, sem ennžį eiga tvo bankanna, krefjast žess aš Sešlabankinn breyti eignum žeirra ķ alvöru pening (gjaldeyri). Raunverulega į Sešlabankinn engan gjaldeyri, žvķ aš hann er allur tekinn aš lįni. Rķkisstjórnin hefur skuldsett rķkiš svo hrošalega, aš vextir af erlendum lįnum nema įrlega um 100 milljöršum Króna. Snjóhengjan veldur gjaldeyrishöftum og engin möguleiki er aš leysa žau nema bręša Snjóhengjuna. Sś ašgerš gerir fęrt aš leišrétta skuldir heimilanna.

Žegar Kanadadalur/Rķkisdalur hefur veriš tekinn upp veršur Krónan įfram į įbyrgš Sešlabankans um tiltekinn tķma. Viš gjaldmišlaskiptin fęrist hagkerfiš yfir į nżgja gjaldmišilinn og žótt Krónan lękki ķ verši, hefur žaš engin önnur įhrif en aš skuldbindingar ķ Krónum lękka aš veršmęti. Hagkerfiš hefur fengiš langžrįšan stöšugleika, er laust viš gjaldeyrishöft og möguleikar opnast til aš bęta stöšu heimilanna. 

 

 Snjóhengjan veldur gjaldeyrishöftum

og engin möguleiki er aš leysa žau nema bręša Snjóhengjuna.

Sś ašgerš gerir fęrt aš leišrétta skuldir heimilanna.


»Fastgengi« tryggir sjįlfkrafa stöšugleika og aukinn hagvöxt

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

»Fastgengi« tryggir sjįlfkrafa stöšugleika og aukinn hagvöxt.

Fyrst birt 16. aprķl 2013.

 

Loftur Altice Žorsteinsson.

Fjįrmagn ķ umferš er annars vegar peningar sem śtgefnir eru af myntslįttu (sešlabanka, myntrįši eša erlendir peningar) og hins vegar skuldbindingar sem einstaklingar og fyrirtęki gera meš gjaldmišilinn sem višmiš. Ef peningakerfi vęri gert upp myndu skuldbindingarnar žurrkast śt, en eftir standa peningarnir.

Ef um er aš ręša fullkominn sżndarpening (fiat money), stendur engin stošmynt eša önnur veršmęti į bak viš hann, peningurinn er einskis virši. Ef peningurinn er alvöru (real money), žį er hęgt aš skipta honum öllum hjį myntslįttunni fyrir alžjóšlega stošmynt og bókhald peningakerfisins gengur žį upp. Myntrįš į alltaf stošmynt til aš skipta fyrir śtgefinn pening. Undir stjórn sešlabanka liggur įstandiš einhver stašar į milli, en enginn veit hver raunveruleg staša er.

Įn óešlilegra afskipta rķkisvaldsins, ręšst  fjįrmagn ķ umferš af efnahagslegum umsvifum ķ hagkerfinu. Aukning fjįrmagns ķ umferš er merki um hrašari śtgįfu skuldbindinga, eša meiri žörf fyrir sešla og mynt. Vegna tęknižróunar er nśna ekki jafn mikil žörf fyrir peninga og įšur var, heldur eru skuldbindingar geršar ķ auknum męli rafręnt. Ekki er hęgt aš auka fjįrmagn ķ umferš, hvort sem um er aš ręša peninga eša skuldbindingar, nema eftirspurn sé eftir žvķ.

Sś hugmynd aš višskiptabankar gefi śt peninga er röng. Bankarnir gefa śt skuldbindingar og žaš er verkefni eftirlitsašila aš gęta žess aš skuldir og eignir umfram eiginfé standist į, hjį hverjum banka. Aukinn hraši ķ innlįnum og śtlįnum bankanna er ekki merki um aukna śtgįfu peninga, heldur betri nżtingu veršmęta.

Hvaš er veršbólga?

Veršbólga er hękkun į verši vöru og žjónustu, frį einum tķma til annars. Hśn stafar oft af tveimur įstęšum. Innri įstęša veršbólgu stafar öšru fremur af hagvexti og til lengri tķma hlżtur žessi veršbólga aš vera ķ samręmi viš uppsafnašan hagvöxt. Ytri įstęša veršbólgu er oftast gengisfall gjaldmišilsins og getur aušveldlega fariš fullkomlega śr böndum. Įstęšan fyrir óšaveršbólgu er ekki sķšur huglęg en efnahagsleg. 

Veršbólga stafi žvķ ekki af  aukningu į peningamagni ķ umferš. Hvorki er hęgt aš neyša in į hagkerfiš peningum né skuldbindingum. Žaš er efnahagsįstand hagkerfisins sem kallar į aukningu eša minnkum peningamagns. Ef til dęmis veršlag hefur hękkaš um 50%, žį veršur fjįrmagn ķ umferš aš vera 50% meira, til aš žjóna sama tilgangi og įšur. Žaš er žvķ verbólgan sem kemur į undan aukningu peningamagns, en ekki į eftir.

Hvernig er hęgt aš minnka veršbólgu?

Til aš skapa stöšugleika, sem merkir minni veršbólgu og af stöšugleika leišir minni eignabruni og meiri kaupmįttur, er naušsynlegt aš koma į alvöru fastgengi. Einungis tķmabundiš gagn getur veriš aš tylltu-gengi, žvķ aš žaš fyrirkomulag gengis hrynur innan skamms. Eini munurinn į flotgengi og tylltu-gengi er aš flotgengi fellur jafnt og žétt, en tyllt-gengi ķ stökkum.

Fastgengi veršur ekki komiš į, nema leggja Sešlabankann nišur og taka upp myntrįš, eša taka ķ notkun alžjóšlegan gjaldmišil. Aušvelt er aš skipta į milli žessara tveggja forma fastgengis, en stofnun myntrįšs tekur lengri tķma. Alžjóšlegan gjaldmišil er hęgt aš taka upp į viku, en myntrįš žarf 12 mįnuši, žvķ aš fyrirkomulag žess veršur aš festa ķ Stjórnarskrįna.

Myntrįš į Ķslandi žarf aš hafa stošmynt ķ varasjóši, sem nemur um 50 milljöršum Króna. Ešlilegt er aš Sešlabankinn leysi śt meš gjaldeyri žį 45 milljarša sem hann er meš śtistandandi ķ Krónum. Rķkiš leggur til myntrįšsins žann gjaldeyri sem į vantar, en fęr sķšar til eignar žann myntgróša sem myndast hjį myntrįšinu.


Įbyrgš og śrręši ķ efnahagsmįlum

  
  
null   Samstaša žjóšar
   
NATIONAL UNITY COALITION                                                           
   Barįttusamtök fyrir sjįlfstęšu rķki į Ķslandi og fullveldisréttindum almennings.
   Stöndum vörš um Stjórnarskrį Lżšveldisins.

  

Įbyrgš og śrręši ķ efnahagsmįlum.

Fyrst birt į vef Evrópunefndar Sjįlfstęšisflokks 11. janśar 2009.

Loftur Altice Žorsteinsson.

Žęr efnahags-žrengingar sem Ķslendsk žjóš gengur nś ķ gegnum, eru ekki nįttśruhamfarir žótt sumir reyni aš koma žeirri hugsum inn ķ huga fólks. Megin-orsökin er ekki "efnahags-bóla sem sprakk", "lausafjįr-skortur bankanna", eša "mistök bankastjóra Sešlabankans". Žrįtt fyrir aš žessir žęttir allir hafi komiš viš sögu, mega allir vita, aš hagkerfi Ķslands bżr viš kerfisvanda, sem var megin-orsök efnahags-hrunsins. Skiptigengi Krónunnar féll og žar meš stöšugleiki alls hagkerfisins.

Öllum er frjįlst aš hafa sķna skošun į efnahagslegum stöšugleika. Ég žekki fólk sem telur aš yfirstandandi kreppa sé naušsynleg og geri sama gagn og hundahreinsun ķ barįttu viš sullaveiki. Flestir eiga erfitt meš aš samžykkja žetta višhorf og telja žaš ganga nęrst hugleišingum um sjįlfsmorš.

Efnahagskreppur hafa gengiš yfir öll samfélög og eru žvķ alžjóšlegt fyrirbęri. Um žetta fyrirbęri hafa žvķ margir hugsaš og um žaš hafa veriš ritašar langar ritgeršir. Ekki er žvķ śr vegi, aš gefa gaum aš nokkrum kjarnyrtum ummęlum valinkunnra manna.

Karl August Fritz Schiller (1911 - 1994), sem var višskiptarįšherra Žżšskalands 1966 til 1972 og jafnframt fjįrmįlarįšherra 1971 til 1972, mun hafa sagt:

"Stöšugur gjaldmišill er vissulega ekki allt, en įn stöšugs gjaldmišils er allt annaš einskis virši."

Annar Žjóšverji aš nafni Ludwig Wilhelm Erhard (1897 - 1977), sem 1963 til 1966 var forveri Schiller ķ embętti višskiptarįšherra, hafši einnig skošanir į efnahagsmįlum, sem hugsanlega eiga erindi til okkar. Hann sagši:

"Viš ęttum ekki aš lįta eins og žekking į hagfręši sé einkaréttur einhverra sjįlfskipašra sérfręšinga, sem ķ valdi sértękrar vitneskju eša almennrar rökfimi žykjast allt vita. Nei, allir žegnar landsins verša aš kunna skil į hagfręši-lögmįlum og vera fęrir um aš leggja mat į žau. Hér er um aš ręša atriši sem varša stjórnarfar ķ landinu og stöšugleika efnahagslķfsins. Žetta eru atriši sem skipta okkur öll miklu mįli."

Skošum einnig hvaš Fritz Leutwiler (1924 - 1997), fyrrverandi bankastjóri sešlabankans ķ Svisslandi, hefur aš segja um veršbólgu:

"Veršbólga hefur žį sérstöšu, aš vera mikilvirkasta tęki hinna fįu rķku til aš verša rķkari og hinna mörgu fįtęku til aš verša fįtękari."

Žeir sem hafa sömu afstöšu til efnahagslegra kollsteypa og žeir erlendu menn sem aš framan greinir, ęttu aš kynna sér hvaša möguleikar eru til aš foršast slķkt. Lausnin er fólgin ķ aš leggja nišur Sešlabanka Ķslands og taka upp žver-öfuga stefnu viš peningastefnu hans. Slķk stefna er śtfęrš undir stjórn Myntrįšs og ef rétt er aš mįlum stašiš, er 100% öruggt aš efnahagslegur stöšugleiki nęst.

Žeir sem leggja trśnaš į žessar fullyršingar mķnar, vilja ešlilega vita orsakir žess aš sešlabanki og myntrįš eru aš flestu leyti andstęšir pólar. Eftirfarandi eru nokkrar žeirra spurninga sem koma viš sögu.

  • Hver er munurinn į fljótandi gengi (floating exchange rate) og tylltu gengi (pegged exchange rate), sem eru ašferšir sešlabanka og hinsvegar föstu gengi (fixed exchange rate) sem er ašferš myntrįšs ?

  • Hvers vegna skiptir mįli, aš gjaldmišill lands hafi 100% bakstušning af erlendum gjaldeyri ?

  • Hver er munurinn į torgreindri peningastefnu sešlabanka og reglu-bundinni peningastefnu myntrįšs ?

Sešlabankar segjast hafa efnahagslegan stöšugleika aš markmiši. Raunveruleikinn er sį, aš oftar en ekki hella žeir olķu į eldinn. Śrręši žeirra eru verri en vandamįliš. Til aš halda gengi gjaldmišilsins stöšugu, hefur Sešlabankinn tvęr meginašferšir. Annars vegar er genginu tyllt viš myntkörfu eša sterkan gjaldmišil og gefin fögur fyrirheit um aš žaš sé nś fast. Hin leišin er aš lįta gengiš fljóta og trśa blint į, aš gjaldeyris-markašur finni hiš eina rétta gengi į hverjum tķma.

Bįšar ašferšir sešlabankanna eru gagnslausar, žótt žęr séu hęttulausar žegar efnahagsumhverfiš er rólegt. Um leiš og eitthvaš reynir į gjaldmišilinn bregšast bįšar ašferšir. Ķ raun eru bįšar ašferšir flotgengi og eini munur žeirra er žaš śtlit sem fall-ferill Krónunnar hefur. Į aš lįta feguršarskyn rįša vali peningastefnunnar ?

Meginverkefni peningastefnu sešlabankanna er aš žjóna pólitķskum öflum en ekki efnahagslegum žörfum almennings. Enginn tekur mark į innistęšulausum yfirlżsingum sešlabanka um aš gengiš standi traustum fótum, enda vinna žeir sjįlfir oftast einaršlega gegn yfirlżstum markmišum. Meš reglulegu millibili missa sešlabankar tökin į efnahagsmįlunum og koma hagkerfunum į kaldan klakann. Óšaveršbólga tekur viš af gengisfalli og almenningur fęr aš blęša fyrir mistökin.

Peningar ķ umferš eru įvķsun į gjaldeyrisforša žess sem er śtgefandi gjaldmišilsins. Handhafar peninganna hafa veitt śtgefandanum vaxtalaust lįn. Gjaldeyrisforšinn er baktrygging gjaldmišilsins og mikilvęgt aš sś baktrygging sé 100%, aš öšrum kosti er gjaldmišillinn of hįtt skrįšur og hlżtur aš lękka fljótlega. Meš öšrum oršum, gengisfall stafar af eyšslu umfram tekjur, sem leišir til neikvęšrar eignastöšu landsins. Gjaldeyrinn er hin raunverulega eign, ekki óljós loforš yfirvalda eša tilvķsun ķ aušlindir ķ landinu.

Vilji menn ķ alvöru skapa stöšugleika ķ hagkerfi, er myntrįš eina lausnin. Myntrįš starfar eftir föstum ósveigjanlegum reglum, sem tryggja stöšugt og fast gengi gjaldmišilsins. Višfangsefni myntrįšs er aš gefa śt gjaldmišil landsins, til dęmis Ķslendskan dollar (ISD) og varšveita stoš-mynt (anchor currency), sem ķ okkar tilfelli er ešlilegt aš sé US-dollar (USD). Bezt er aš hafa skiptihlutfalliš 1 ISD = 1 USD, žvķ aš žannig verša öll višskipti meš bįša gjaldmišlana aušveld innanlands.

Heldsta įstęša žess aš sešlabankar njóta ekki trausts, er sś aš žeir fylgja svonefndri torgreindri peningastefnu (discretionary monetary policy). Ķ samręmi viš žessa stefnu lķta sešlabankar svo į, aš žaš sé žeirra einkamįl hvernig fjįrmįlum žjóšarinnar er hagaš. Öšrum kemur žaš hreinlega ekki viš hvaš sešlabankinn er aš sżsla og žaš žykir kostur į žeim bę, aš koma almenningi į óvart.

Myntrįš fylgja hins vegar stefnu sem nefnd er reglu-bundin peningastefna (rule-bound monetary policy). Einkenni žessarar stefnu er aš allar reglur varšandi gjaldmišilinn liggja fyrir og eru aušskiljanlegar. Višskiptalķfiš įkvešur til dęmis peningamagn ķ umferš og vaxtastigiš įkvešst af vaxtastigi į myntsvęši stošmyntarinnar. Viš aš halda genginu föstu, hęttir gengisfall aš bęta ķ veršbólguna og jafnframt stöšvast eignabruninn. Lįnskjaravķsitala veršur óžörf, žvķ aš gjaldmišillinn sjįlfur tekur viš af vķsitölunni, sem veršmętatrygging.

Žeir sem vilja frekari upplżsingar um upptöku Ķslendsks Dollars, meš Myntrįši og baktryggingu USD, geta fundiš žęr hér:

http://samstada-thjodar.blog.is/blog/samstada-thjodar/entry/1230005/


« Fyrri sķša | Nęsta sķša »

Innskrįning

Ath. Vinsamlegast kveikiš į Javascript til aš hefja innskrįningu.

Hafšu samband